Copyright

Arrow's Impossibility Theorem & Its Use in Voting

Arrow's Impossibility Theorem & Its Use in Voting
Coming up next: The Problem of Apportionment in Politics

You're on a roll. Keep up the good work!

Take Quiz Watch Next Lesson
 Replay
Your next lesson will play in 10 seconds
  • 0:02 Arrow's Impossibility Theorem
  • 0:48 Brief Explanation of…
  • 2:10 Properties of Fair Voting
  • 3:24 Example of Theorem at Work
  • 4:48 Excluded Voting Methods
  • 5:11 Lesson Summary
Add to Add to Add to

Want to watch this again later?

Log in or sign up to add this lesson to a Custom Course.

Log in or Sign up

Timeline
Autoplay
Autoplay
Speed

Recommended Lessons and Courses for You

Lesson Transcript
Instructor: Maria Airth

Maria has a Doctorate of Education and over 15 years of experience teaching psychology and math related courses at the university level.

This lesson reviews Arrow's Impossibility Theorem, which states that there is no preferential voting method that adheres to reasonable fairness principles. An example is used to illustrate his theorem.

Arrow's Impossibility Theorem

When you think of the impossible, what do you think of? Many things are just impossible. You can't have windows that open on a submarine (well, at least not that open when the sub is underwater). Years ago, man thought that human flight was impossible, and it certainly is impossible to actually ride on a bird's back and fly as they fly. But what else is impossible?

What would you say if I told you that a fair voting system is impossible? Would you agree? That is exactly what a researcher named Kenneth Arrow set out to show with his Arrow's Impossibility Theorem. Also called 'Arrow's Paradox', the theorem states that it is not possible to obtain a preferential result in an election while also adhering to principles of fair voting.

Brief Explanation of Preferential Voting

Wow, so this guy really thought that there was no fair way to vote? Not exactly, he showed there was no ideal means of preferential voting. Preferential voting is a method of voting (which Arrow called a social welfare function) that allows voters to rank each candidate in order of preference instead of just choosing the most preferred candidate.

For example, if you were having a dinner party, you might want to serve dessert. Instead of just informing your guests what you will serve, maybe you want to be democratic and let everyone vote on it. If the choices are cookies, cake or ice cream, you might have your guests submit their choices in order. One guest might respond with, 'I like cake, then ice cream, and last cookies.' That is one vote; each vote is listed in order of preference.

Here's a chart showing the results from all nine guests' preferences:

example chart of data

It shows that four of your guests prefer cookies over ice cream over cake. Three would rather have ice cream than cake or cookies. And only two would prefer cake, but would want ice cream before cookies.

Arrow might call this chart the 'Will of the People', and he would believe that the voting method used to obtain it should have at least three reasonable properties.

Properties of Fair Voting

Arrow said that it would be reasonable to assume that a fair voting method has:

  • No Dictators, meaning that no individual person's ranking should determine the rankings outcome each time. Basically, no single person should have the power to sway the vote every time. This doesn't mean that a vote can't be decided by ONE ballot, but it just can't be the same individual person's ballot that decides it each time. That would be a dictator.
  • Pareto Efficiency, meaning if voters prefer Option 1 to Option 2, then the outcome should show Option 1 ranked highest.
  • Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives, meaning if Option 1 is ranked higher than Option 2, removing Option 3 should not alter the relative rankings of Options 1 and 2. This property relates to the removal of the losing option. It makes sense that if you remove an option that has already lost, the results for the other options should not change.

Amazingly, Arrow's Impossibility Theorem postulates that when there are three or more options, there is no preferential voting method that can satisfy all three of these reasonable fair voting assumptions.

Example of Theorem at Work

Let's return to the desired desserts from the dinner party you are planning. In the results, cookies have received the highest number of first place votes, so cookies would win, right?

But, wait! Look at those numbers again. Only four people would actually prefer cookies over everything else. The other five (the actual majority in this case) would prefer ANYTHING to cookies. So, is it fair that cookies will win when the majority of people actually don't want them?

To unlock this lesson you must be a Study.com Member.
Create your account

Register to view this lesson

Are you a student or a teacher?

Unlock Your Education

See for yourself why 30 million people use Study.com

Become a Study.com member and start learning now.
Become a Member  Back
What teachers are saying about Study.com
Try it risk-free for 30 days

Earning College Credit

Did you know… We have over 200 college courses that prepare you to earn credit by exam that is accepted by over 1,500 colleges and universities. You can test out of the first two years of college and save thousands off your degree. Anyone can earn credit-by-exam regardless of age or education level.

To learn more, visit our Earning Credit Page

Transferring credit to the school of your choice

Not sure what college you want to attend yet? Study.com has thousands of articles about every imaginable degree, area of study and career path that can help you find the school that's right for you.

Create an account to start this course today
Try it risk-free for 30 days!
Create an account
Support